The Economic and Fiscal Effects of Repealing Federal Estate, Giftand Generation-Skipping Taxes

Report Taxes

The Economic and Fiscal Effects of Repealing Federal Estate, Giftand Generation-Skipping Taxes

November 15, 2002 37 min read Download Report
Alfredo Goyburu
Policy Analyst, Transportation and Infrastructure
On June 7, 2001, President George W. Bush signed into law the Economic Growth and Tax Reform Reconciliation Act of 2001 (EGTRRA),1 a package of tax reductions and policy changes that include temporary reduc­tions in three federal estate transfer taxes (FETTs). The law mandates the phaseout of the federal estate tax and the federal generation-skipping tax by January 1, 2010, and the reduction of the federal gift tax. The provisions of the law, however, are scheduled to expire on January 1, 2011, at which time all three federal estate or wealth transfer taxes will return to their 2001 pre-tax cut levels. Analysts in the Center for Data Analysis (CDA) at The Heritage Foundation estimated the effects of an immediate and permanent repeal of all three federal estate transfer taxes. These effects include changes in tax revenue, gross domestic product (GDP), interest rates, employment levels, personal income, and inflation. Any of these macroeconomic changes could affect tax revenues significantly. The findings of the CDA analysis show that eliminating the taxes entirely would yield strong economic and fiscal benefits for the country. Immediate and permanent repeal of the FETTs would improve the nation's eco­nomic performance over the next 10 years, create thousands of jobs, and raise disposable income without increasing cumulative federal deficits or publicly held debt by the end of the 10 years. Moreover, under the current tax code, repealing the FETTs would, over the fol­lowing 10 years, not reduce federal revenues, but would increase them and provide further opportunity for additional tax relief. Specifically, compared with what would occur under the current law, an immediate and permanent repeal of the three FETTs on Janu­ary 1, 2003, would have the following benefi­cial effects. For example, in fiscal year (FY) 2012 alone, repeal would:

Add $14.7 billion (adjusted for inflation)2 to the GDP;

Add 118,000 jobs to the U.S. economy;

Reduce nationwide unemployment by 27,000 persons;

Raise U.S. personal disposable income by an inflation-adjusted $11 billion;

Increase non-residential net capital stock by $25.1 billion and lower the user cost of capital by 0.3 percent;

Leave relative price levels and key interest rates unaffected, in spite of the stimulating effect repeal would have on economic activity; and

Reduce the nation's publicly held debt by $5.7 billion.

The current plan to restore the FETTs in 2011 will substantially curtail these substantial benefits.

 

How Estate Transfer Taxes affect Economic Behavior

Several studies have found that the federal estate transfer taxes reduce economic growth. For example, in a 1998 study, former DRI/McGraw-Hill economists Richard F. Fullenbaum and Mari­ana A. McNeill cited three reasons for this overall effect.3

According to these experts, the FETTs:

     Cause considerable resources to be diverted away from economically productive activities and toward tax avoidance activities;

     Raise the user cost of capital, biasing affected owners of capital toward consumption and away from investment; and

     Reduce labor force participation.4

Henry J. Aaron, a Brookings Institution scholar, and Alicia Munnell, a former Clinton Administra­tion economic adviser, pointed out in 1992 that the FETTs created substantial rewards for tax avoidance activities. They echoed Columbia law school professor George Cooper's description of the levies as "voluntary taxes." Out of $123 billion transferred across generations in 1986, a mere $36 billion was reported on estate tax returns, resulting in $6 billion in federal collections that year. "Informed observers," these experts noted, "think that decedents could have avoided even this mod­est toll if they had taken the time to do so."5 Tax avoidance requires the services of skilled estate planners. The federal estate transfer taxes nurture an industry that employs thousands of highly educated and highly remunerated profes­sionals. In the early 1990s, the American Bar Asso­ciation reported that approximately 16,000 (5 percent) of its members described their area of concentration as trust, probate, and estate law. This total does not include the number of accoun­tants and financial planners who offer estate-plan­ning services.6 Tax avoidance activity has several facets. All involve reducing the size of the estate by the time the property owner dies to avoid the death tax- basically a second tax on assets purchased with after-tax income. Common methods of tax avoid­ance include making direct transfers from the estate to such legal entities as trusts or limited partnerships, or as carefully planned gifts.7 Another is replacing monetary compensation for highly paid corporate executives with life insur­ance. Yet another is the use of experts to procure a low estimate of the value of the estate.8Heritage economist William Beach argues that the FETTs are a significant determinant of the cost of capital-the higher the level of such taxes, the higher the required rate of return on capital invest­ments. The reason, he explains, is that "when indi­viduals begin to see that their income and investment efforts will produce a future taxable estate, they…increase their earnings requirements to build the funds needed to pay the future wealth transfer taxes."9 This higher earnings requirement can be observed in the national economy as a higher user cost of capital than would otherwise prevail. The higher user cost of capital discourages investment and creates a bias among affected property owners in favor of consumption. MIT economist James M. Poterba estimates that federal estate transfer taxes add at least 1.3 percent to the cost of owning capi­tal in the United States.10 Fullenbaum and McNeill describe estate transfer taxes as reductions in the after-tax wages of affected workers.11  Economic theory suggests that, all other things being equal, public policies that broadly reduce after-tax wages reduce labor force participation rates.12 According to Beach, this reduction reached 97,200 persons in 1996.13Eliminating the FETTs permanently and imme­diately would reverse these damaging effects on the national economy. Thousands of federal estate tax lawyers would be freed to engage in activities more closely associated with economic growth; the user cost of capital in the national economy would fall, making more types of investment immediately attractive and thus spurring investments overall; and a disincentive that keeps thousands of Ameri­cans out of the labor force would disappear.14

The 2011 phaseout and restoration of the fed­eral estate tax (FET) and the federal generation-skipping tax (GST) enacted in last year's tax cut law will do very little to alter the tax avoidance behaviors described above. No estate holder with a reasonable expectation of living past January 1, 2011, will expect to realize the tax relief, since the phaseout affects only the estates of those who die before that date. A person expecting to live past 2010 will adjust his economic behavior as if the FET and the GST had not changed at all. Consequently, the smaller the share of prospec­tive estate tax filers expecting to die between 2002 and 2010, the less the national economy will bene­fit from the one-year repeal. CDA analysts estimate that under current law at least 3 million FETT returns will be filed during the period 2003- 2027.15 Of these returns, less than 16 percent are expected to be filed before 2011.16Thus, EGTRRA provides no estate tax relief at all for the vast majority of taxpayers who should expect to be affected by FETTs, in addition to which the bulk of potential economic benefits that the nation could see from estate tax reform will not be observed under the current law. However, Con­gress could unlock these effects through an imme­diate and permanent repeal of the federal estate transfer taxes.

 

The Heritage Analysis of FETT Repeal

In addition to these behavioral aspects of tax policy changes, the CDA analysts considered the interaction between FETT repeal and capital gains tax collections, as well as between FETT repeal and federal spending.

Capital Gains Offset. Without further tax reform, repealing the FETTs immediately and per­manently would mean higher capital gains tax rev­enues. The reason: The current statute regarding the FETTs exempts inheritors from taxes on gains unrealized, during the decedent's lifetime, on the transferred property. Inheritors are allowed to raise the base value of the transferred property to its fair market value at the time the decedent dies. This exemption is known as the "step-up" of the basis on transferred property. According to the Joint Committee on Taxation (JCT), this exemption would amount to $216.6 billion in uncollected capital gains tax revenue in the five years from 2002-2006.17 The mere repeal of the FETTs would abolish this capital gains tax exemption and could subject the inheritors to this increased tax levy. To relieve the tax burden at death and reduce the need for the heir to liquidate assets prema­turely, CDA analysts incorporated a capital gains exclusion of $1 million on transferred estates and a $3 million exclusion on spousal transfers. Such a provision severs "the link between payment of the tax and death and allows heirs to select the timing of the realization of capital gains."18 CDA analysts estimated the amounts of this exclusion for the years 2003-2012 using JCT estimates and incor­porated them into the economic impact study of FETT repeal. (These estimates are shown in Table 1 in the Appendix.) Congress could eliminate this capital gains off­set, of course, by repealing the capital gains tax or, at a minimum, ensuring that any additional tax revenue arising from the capital gains offset is used for further tax relief.

Federal Spending. CDA analysts assumed that overall federal government spending would be adjusted according to changes in tax collections caused by eliminating the FETTs. This assumption assures that there would be virtually no change in the cumulative federal surplus during the 10-year period from fiscal years 2003-2012.19 Year-to-year variations in surpluses do occur. CDA analysts channeled these spending changes through adjust­ments in federal non-defense spending and federal grants-in-aid to state and local governments.

A Dynamic Analysis of Immediate FETT Repeal

CDA analysts used the DRI-WEFA U.S. Macro­economic Model to conduct the dynamic simula­tion of the elimination of the FETTs.20 They performed the simulation using a version of the September 2002 DRI-WEFA long-term forecast, which they modified to incorporate the economic and budgetary assumptions published by the Con­gressional Budget Office (CBO) in August 2002.21 This adapted forecast can be used to find the effects of policy changes on the economy and the federal budget through a dynamic rather than a static analysis. A static analysis of the potential effects of a tax policy change would examine only its effects on tax collections. This method could omit important effects that changes in tax policy exert on the econ­omy. For example, if a proposed tax reduction is likely to improve national economic performance, that performance could in turn increase tax collec­tions, which could partially offset the federal reve­nue losses caused by the tax reduction. Static analysis would be likely to omit the policy's benefi­cial effect on the economy and therefore overesti­mate the cost of that particular tax reduction. A dynamic analysis, which considers the effects of the tax policy change on the economy, would more accurately estimate the overall effects of the tax policy change on both the national economy and on tax collections.22
Heritage economists performed a dynamic anal­ysis of FETT repeal by changing policy-related variables23 in the adapted DRI-WEFA model to simulate the effects on the national economy. They then conducted an economic simulation using the adapted model and the changed policy-related variables to find the effects of the policy change on the U.S. macroeconomy. They compared the val­ues of key macroeconomic quantities before and after simulation, attributing the observed differ­ences to the policy change. This method allowed CDA analysts to identify the effects on the national economy of that change, in this case FETT repeal. (See Appendix, Table 2.)24Take, as an example, the dynamic analysis of a hypothetical tax policy change. Suppose the simu­lation corresponding to that policy change yields a GDP for 2005 that is $1 billion higher than its value in the original CBO projection. In this case, the tax policy change would be said to have added $1 billion to the GDP for 2005. In other words, one may say that the GDP would be $1 billion higher in 2005 under the tax policy than without it.

 

Benefits of Eliminating Estate Transfer Taxes

Table 2 in the Appendix displays the difference in economic results between the policy of repeal and the current-law policy as reflected in the adapted DRI-WEFA model. The table shows that immediate and permanent FETT repeal would increase the nation's economic growth compared with what would happen under the currently planned temporary phaseout of such taxes. In the absence of further tax reform, immediate and per­manent repeal would increase federal revenues over the following 10 years as well as:

     Strengthen economic growth. By the end of FY 2012, GDP would be $14.7 billion higher (after adjusting for inflation) under FETT repeal than it would under current law (as pro­jected by the CBO). Moreover, average GDP between 2003 and 2012 would run $10.6 bil­lion higher.

     Create more job opportunities. With the FETTs eliminated, the economy would support 118,000 more jobs by 2012 than it would under current law. Between 2003 and 2012, the average national employment level would run 104,000 jobs higher under repeal than it would otherwise.

     Reduce unemployment. Immediate and per­manent repeal of the FETTs also would reduce unemployment by 27,000 persons in 2012. The average number of unemployed for the 10 years following repeal would be 13,000 lower than without repeal.

     Raise disposable personal income. Under elimination of the FETTs, personal disposable income would be $11.0 billion higher by the end of FY 2012, with immediate repeal, than it would without it. Average personal disposable income during 2003-2012 would be $10.3 billion higher under repeal.

     Increase non-residential investment. Repeal of the estate tax would improve the investment environment enough to raise investment by $7.3 billion (adjusted for inflation) by 2012. Non-residential capital stock would be $25.1 billion higher. The user cost of capital would be 0.3 percent lower by 2012 than it would be if the FETTs were not eliminated.

     Leave relative price levels and key interest rates unaffected. In spite of the stimulating effect FETT repeal would have on economic activity, it would not significantly affect either the consumer price index (CPI) or key govern­ment interest rates.

     A slight decline in the federal publicly held debt during 2012. During the first years after repeal of the FETTs, the decline in federal reve­nue would raise the federal publicly held debt above where it would be under current law, reaching an inflation-adjusted $22.1 billion above the CBO's projection for 2007. This margin would then decline, reaching $5.7 bil­lion below the CBO-projected level by 2012.

 

Conclusion

The tax cuts President Bush signed into law last year incorporate the phasing out and temporary abolition of the federal estate tax (FET) and gener­ation-skipping taxes (GST). This move signaled Congress's willingness to consider key reforms of this tax.

However, the law allows the FET and other estate or wealth transfer taxes to return in 2011. These estate taxes have damaging economic effects, slowing economic growth and reducing potential increases in employment. A temporary phasing out of the federal estate transfer taxes will not address either of these detriments. As this CDA analysis shows, after just 10 years, an immediate and permanent repeal of the FET and other federal estate transfer taxes would strengthen economic activity, create hundreds of thousands of new jobs, bolster disposable income by $11 billion, reduce unemployment, and raise revenue while leaving the nation with a lower fed­eral publicly held debt by FY 2011. -Alfredo B. Goyburu is a Policy Analyst in the Center for Data Analysis at The Heritage Foundation.

APPENDIX

Methodology

Heritage Foundation economists in the Center for Data Analysis (CDA) followed a two-step pro­cedure in identifying the 10-year economic and budgetary impact of an immediate and permanent repeal of the federal estate transfer taxes (FETTs) effective January 1, 2003.

First, CDA analysts applied Congressional Bud­get Office (CBO) projections for FETT collections under current law.25 As a working assumption, they used the negative of these collection estimates as a preliminary estimate of the federal revenue that would be lost under FETT repeal. To this esti­mate, CDA analysts applied a projection of the additional capital gains taxes that would be col­lected as a result of an FETT repeal, with a first $1 million exemption plus a $3 million spousal exemption, which produced a modified prelimi­nary estimate for federal revenue loss. (See Table 1.)26

Using this modified preliminary estimate as an ultimate forecast of the federal revenue loss result­ing from FETT repeal, however, would be to implement an erroneous static approach to an analysis of the effects of that tax policy change. The more correct (dynamic) approach is to take account of the macroeconomic effects of the tax policy change. These effects include changes in gross domestic product (GDP), interest rates, employment levels, personal income, and infla­tion. Any of these macroeconomic quantities could affect tax revenues significantly.

Second, CDA analysts introduced the modified preliminary estimate of tax revenue change into an especially adapted version of the DRI-WEFA U.S. Macroeconomic Model.27 They then processed the simulation and noted changes in key macroeco­nomic and budget variables compared with their values in the original adapted version of the model. Differences in these key variables were attributed to the response of the U.S. economy and federal budget to the tax policy change-that is, the dynamic response. (See Table 2.)

The Simulation28

The DRI-WEFA model contains a number of variables used to simulate policy changes. CDA analysts introduced static tax revenue and eco­nomic behavior change estimates to the model in order to find the dynamic responses of the U.S. economy and federal budget during 2003-2012 to immediate and permanent repeal of the FETTs. These include:

  Civilian Labor Force. Heritage economist William W. Beach estimated in 1996 that the FETTs reduced the labor supply by 97,200 in 1996.29 CDA analysts revised this estimate to 103,900 using more recent information on the nation's civilian labor force growth rate from the Bureau of Labor Statistics. They adjusted the variable controlling labor supply in the model accordingly, phasing in the 103,900-worker increase over two years.

Non-NIPA30Federal Government Revenue. This variable measures taxes paid to the federal government not coming from income flows in the economy, such as the estate tax and the capital gains tax. CDA economists adjusted this variable according to the net static change in federal collections of these two types of tax resulting from the tax policy reform.

     Business Sector Price Index. CDA analysts reduced this variable during the forecast period in order to reflect lowered compliance costs for the business sector resulting from FETT repeal. The adjustments corresponded to a reduction in business sector costs of 30 cents for every dollar that would have been collected in federal estate transfer taxes. This ratio is based on previous research cited by former DRI/McGraw-Hill economists Richard Fullen­baum and Mariana McNeill.31

Corporate AAA Bond Rate. MIT economist James M. Poterba estimated in a 2000 study that eliminating wealth transfer taxes would reduce the required yield on investment by at least 1.3 percent.[32] CDA analysts lowered the corporate AAA bond rate within the model in order to reflect this 1.3 percent reduction.

Federal Non-Defense Spending Variables. CDA economists adjusted federal spending in order to compensate for the projected changes in federal collections resulting from FETT repeal. This adjustment assured that the tax policy reform would not cause a substantial change in cumulative federal deficits during the forecast period. The adjusted variables controlled direct federal non-defense spending and federal grants-in-aid to state and local gov­ernments.



[1]Public Law 107-16.

[2]All inflation-adjusted dollars referenced in this report are indexed to the 1996 overall price level and thus repre­sent 1996 dollars.

[3]Richard F. Fullenbaum and Mariana A. McNeill, "The Effects of the Federal Estate and Gift Tax on the Aggregate Economy," Research Institute for Small and Emerging Business, Working Paper Series No. 98-01, 1998, pp. 10-11.

[4]William W. Beach, "The Case for Repealing the Estate Tax," Heritage Foundation Backgrounder No. 1091, August 21, 1996, p. 26.

[5]Henry J. Aaron and Alicia Munnell, " Reassessing the Role for Wealth Transfer Taxes," National Tax Journal, Vol. 45, No. 2 (June 1992), pp. 133-134, at .

[6]Ibid., p. 138.

[7]A number of financial counseling firms list transfers to trusts and carefully planned gifts on their Internet sites as key estate planning techniques. See, for example, Prudential Financial at http://www.prudential.com/productsAndServices/0,1474,intPageID%253D1350%2526blnPrinterFriendly%253D0,00.html; Dana S. Beane & Company, P.C., at http://www.dsbc­pas.com/estatetaxplanning/estateplanningtech.html; and Deborah A. Malkin, Attorney at Law, at http://www.malkintrust.com/Avoid-Estate-Taxes.htm (October 25, 2002).

[8]Aaron and Munnell, "Reassessing the Role for Wealth Transfer Taxes," pp. 135, 137.

[9]Beach, "The Case for Repealing the Estate Tax," p. 24.

[10]James M. Poterba, "Estate Tax and After-Tax Investment Returns," in Joel M. Slemrod, ed., Does Atlas Shrug? (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 2000), p. 339. Beach estimates that the FETTs add 3 percent to the cost of owning capital. See Beach, "The Case for Repealing the Estate Tax," p. 24.

[11]Fullenbaum and McNeill, "The Effects of the Federal Estate and Gift Tax on the Aggregate Economy," p. 10.

[12]All other things held constant, economic theory suggests unambiguously that reductions in after-tax wages reduce the number of participants in the labor force, since both the wealth and the substitution effect reinforce one another, rather than offset one another, in this case.

[13]Beach, "The Case for Repealing the Estate Tax," p. 24.

[14]Ibid.

[15]Estimated by extrapolating unpublished projections for estate tax filings by fiscal year performed by the Statistics of Income Program of the Internal Revenue Service.

[16]Projections for estate tax filings through 2010 from unpublished Statistics of Income Program projections.

[17]Joint Committee on Taxation, "Estimates of Federal Tax Expenditures for Fiscal Years 2002-2006," January 17, 2002, p. 23, at http://frwebgate.access.gpo.gov/cgi-bin/getdoc.cgi?dbname=2002_joint_committee_on_taxation&docid=f:76452.pdf.

[18]Fullenbaum and McNeill, "The Effects of the Federal Estate and Gift Tax on the Aggregate Economy," p. 9.

[19]See Appendix, Table 2.

[20]The Center for Data Analysis used the Mark 11 U.S. Macroeconomic Model of DRI-WEFA, Inc. (now known as Global Insight), to conduct this analysis. The model was developed in the late 1960s by Nobel Prize-winning economist Lawrence Klein and several colleagues at the University of Pennsylvania. It is widely used by Fortune 500 companies, prominent federal agencies, and economic forecasting departments. The methodologies, assumptions, conclusions, and opinions herein are entirely the work of Heritage Foundation analysts. They have not been endorsed by, nor do they neces­sarily reflect the views of, the owners of the model.

[21]Congressional Budget Office, "The Budget and Economic Outlook: An Update," August 2002, at http://www.cbo.gov/showdoc.cfm?index=3735&sequence=0.

[22]For a discussion of the shortcomings of static analysis of the effects of tax policy changes, see Daniel J. Mitchell, "The Cor­rect Way to Measure the Revenue Impact of Changes in Tax Rates," Heritage Foundation Backgrounder No. 1544, May 3, 2002, at http://www.heritage.org/Research/Taxes/BG1544.cfm; see also "The Argument for Reality-Based Scoring," Heritage Foundation Web Memo No. 92, March 29, 2002, at http://www.heritage.org/Research/Taxes/WM92.cfm, and Daniel R. Burton, "Reforming the Federal Tax Policy Process," Cato Policy Analysis, forthcoming December 2002.

[23]The variables changed in this simulation for the purpose of modeling FETT repeal are enumerated in the Appendix.

[24]Table 2 shows year-by-year estimates of how repeal of the FETTs would likely change major economic indicators.

[25]Congressional Budget Office, "The Budget and Economic Outlook: An Update," p. 48.

[26]CDA economists applied a staged process to calculate the additional capital gains tax collections. The first stage was to combine historical averages on federal estate tax returns from the IRS Statistics of Income Program and modified pro­jections from the Joint Committee on Taxation on the current-law capital gains tax exclusion at death. These together yielded a projection of the amount of taxable capital gains held in estates over and above the $1 million exemption, without taking into account the higher spousal exemption. The second stage was for CDA analysts to use historical averages to find how much the higher $3 million spousal exemption would subtract from the first projection of tax­able capital gains. The final stage involved applying the long-term capital gains tax rate to the modified projection for non-exempt taxable capital gains to create a projection of the additional capital gains tax collections under FETT repeal.

[27]This version of the model is especially adapted to embody economic and budgetary projections published by the CBO in August 2002.

[28]Readers interested in replicating this analysis should contact the author for further information on how the model was applied.

[29]Beach, "The Case for Repealing the Estate Tax," p. 26.

[30]NIPA stands for National Income and Product Accounts.

[31]Fullenbaum and McNeill, "The Effects of the Federal Estate and Gift Tax on the Aggregate Economy," pp. A1 and A2. These two authors cited four sources for this estimate. The first estimate, by Guest and Associates, L.L.C., was based upon survey data to find the amount that estate holders spent on federal estate tax planning and preparation during 1995; this amount was compared with 1995 FETT collections and yielded a ratio of 30 percent. The second estimate was based upon calcula­tions for FETT compliance costs by Kennesaw State University scholars Joseph Astrachan and Craig Aranoff; the cost was divided by an annual FETT collection total, resulting in a ratio of 32 percent. The third estimate was from Christopher E. Erblich of the Tax and Estate Planning Practice Group, who calculated both compliance and economic disincentive costs resulting from the U.S. federal tax system; Erblich's amount was divided by an annual total for FETT collection, yielding a ratio close to 31.2 percent. Finally, CDA economist William W. Beach provided an estimate of the 1995 cost of compliance with FETT that, when compared to 1995 FETT collections, resulted in a ratio of 29.8 percent.

[32]Poterba, "Estate Tax and After-Tax Investment Returns," p. 339.

APPENDIX

Methodology

Heritage Foundation economists in the Center for Data Analysis (CDA) followed a two-step pro­cedure in identifying the 10-year economic and budgetary impact of an immediate and permanent repeal of the federal estate transfer taxes (FETTs) effective January 1, 2003.

First, CDA analysts applied Congressional Bud­get Office (CBO) projections for FETT collections under current law.25 As a working assumption, they used the negative of these collection estimates as a preliminary estimate of the federal revenue that would be lost under FETT repeal. To this esti­mate, CDA analysts applied a projection of the additional capital gains taxes that would be col­lected as a result of an FETT repeal, with a first $1 million exemption plus a $3 million spousal exemption, which produced a modified prelimi­nary estimate for federal revenue loss. (See Table 1.)26

Using this modified preliminary estimate as an ultimate forecast of the federal revenue loss result­ing from FETT repeal, however, would be to implement an erroneous static approach to an analysis of the effects of that tax policy change. The more correct (dynamic) approach is to take account of the macroeconomic effects of the tax policy change. These effects include changes in gross domestic product (GDP), interest rates, employment levels, personal income, and infla­tion. Any of these macroeconomic quantities could affect tax revenues significantly.

Second, CDA analysts introduced the modified preliminary estimate of tax revenue change into an especially adapted version of the DRI-WEFA U.S. Macroeconomic Model.27 They then processed the simulation and noted changes in key macroeco­nomic and budget variables compared with their values in the original adapted version of the model. Differences in these key variables were attributed to the response of the U.S. economy and federal budget to the tax policy change-that is, the dynamic response. (See Table 2.)

The Simulation28

The DRI-WEFA model contains a number of variables used to simulate policy changes. CDA analysts introduced static tax revenue and eco­nomic behavior change estimates to the model in order to find the dynamic responses of the U.S. economy and federal budget during 2003-2012 to immediate and permanent repeal of the FETTs. These include:

  Civilian Labor Force. Heritage economist William W. Beach estimated in 1996 that the FETTs reduced the labor supply by 97,200 in 1996.29 CDA analysts revised this estimate to 103,900 using more recent information on the nation's civilian labor force growth rate from the Bureau of Labor Statistics. They adjusted the variable controlling labor supply in the model accordingly, phasing in the 103,900-worker increase over two years.

Non-NIPA30Federal Government Revenue. This variable measures taxes paid to the federal government not coming from income flows in the economy, such as the estate tax and the capital gains tax. CDA economists adjusted this variable according to the net static change in federal collections of these two types of tax resulting from the tax policy reform.

     Business Sector Price Index. CDA analysts reduced this variable during the forecast period in order to reflect lowered compliance costs for the business sector resulting from FETT repeal. The adjustments corresponded to a reduction in business sector costs of 30 cents for every dollar that would have been collected in federal estate transfer taxes. This ratio is based on previous research cited by former DRI/McGraw-Hill economists Richard Fullen­baum and Mariana McNeill.31

Corporate AAA Bond Rate. MIT economist James M. Poterba estimated in a 2000 study that eliminating wealth transfer taxes would reduce the required yield on investment by at least 1.3 percent.[32] CDA analysts lowered the corporate AAA bond rate within the model in order to reflect this 1.3 percent reduction.

Federal Non-Defense Spending Variables. CDA economists adjusted federal spending in order to compensate for the projected changes in federal collections resulting from FETT repeal. This adjustment assured that the tax policy reform would not cause a substantial change in cumulative federal deficits during the forecast period. The adjusted variables controlled direct federal non-defense spending and federal grants-in-aid to state and local gov­ernments.



[1]Public Law 107-16.

[2]All inflation-adjusted dollars referenced in this report are indexed to the 1996 overall price level and thus repre­sent 1996 dollars.

[3]Richard F. Fullenbaum and Mariana A. McNeill, "The Effects of the Federal Estate and Gift Tax on the Aggregate Economy," Research Institute for Small and Emerging Business, Working Paper Series No. 98-01, 1998, pp. 10-11.

[4]William W. Beach, "The Case for Repealing the Estate Tax," Heritage Foundation Backgrounder No. 1091, August 21, 1996, p. 26.

[5]Henry J. Aaron and Alicia Munnell, " Reassessing the Role for Wealth Transfer Taxes," National Tax Journal, Vol. 45, No. 2 (June 1992), pp. 133-134, at .

[6]Ibid., p. 138.

[7]A number of financial counseling firms list transfers to trusts and carefully planned gifts on their Internet sites as key estate planning techniques. See, for example, Prudential Financial at http://www.prudential.com/productsAndServices/0,1474,intPageID%253D1350%2526blnPrinterFriendly%253D0,00.html; Dana S. Beane & Company, P.C., at http://www.dsbc­pas.com/estatetaxplanning/estateplanningtech.html; and Deborah A. Malkin, Attorney at Law, at http://www.malkintrust.com/Avoid-Estate-Taxes.htm (October 25, 2002).

[8]Aaron and Munnell, "Reassessing the Role for Wealth Transfer Taxes," pp. 135, 137.

[9]Beach, "The Case for Repealing the Estate Tax," p. 24.

[10]James M. Poterba, "Estate Tax and After-Tax Investment Returns," in Joel M. Slemrod, ed., Does Atlas Shrug? (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 2000), p. 339. Beach estimates that the FETTs add 3 percent to the cost of owning capital. See Beach, "The Case for Repealing the Estate Tax," p. 24.

[11]Fullenbaum and McNeill, "The Effects of the Federal Estate and Gift Tax on the Aggregate Economy," p. 10.

[12]All other things held constant, economic theory suggests unambiguously that reductions in after-tax wages reduce the number of participants in the labor force, since both the wealth and the substitution effect reinforce one another, rather than offset one another, in this case.

[13]Beach, "The Case for Repealing the Estate Tax," p. 24.

[14]Ibid.

[15]Estimated by extrapolating unpublished projections for estate tax filings by fiscal year performed by the Statistics of Income Program of the Internal Revenue Service.

[16]Projections for estate tax filings through 2010 from unpublished Statistics of Income Program projections.

[17]Joint Committee on Taxation, "Estimates of Federal Tax Expenditures for Fiscal Years 2002-2006," January 17, 2002, p. 23, at http://frwebgate.access.gpo.gov/cgi-bin/getdoc.cgi?dbname=2002_joint_committee_on_taxation&docid=f:76452.pdf.

[18]Fullenbaum and McNeill, "The Effects of the Federal Estate and Gift Tax on the Aggregate Economy," p. 9.

[19]See Appendix, Table 2.

[20]The Center for Data Analysis used the Mark 11 U.S. Macroeconomic Model of DRI-WEFA, Inc. (now known as Global Insight), to conduct this analysis. The model was developed in the late 1960s by Nobel Prize-winning economist Lawrence Klein and several colleagues at the University of Pennsylvania. It is widely used by Fortune 500 companies, prominent federal agencies, and economic forecasting departments. The methodologies, assumptions, conclusions, and opinions herein are entirely the work of Heritage Foundation analysts. They have not been endorsed by, nor do they neces­sarily reflect the views of, the owners of the model.

[21]Congressional Budget Office, "The Budget and Economic Outlook: An Update," August 2002, at http://www.cbo.gov/showdoc.cfm?index=3735&sequence=0.

[22]For a discussion of the shortcomings of static analysis of the effects of tax policy changes, see Daniel J. Mitchell, "The Cor­rect Way to Measure the Revenue Impact of Changes in Tax Rates," Heritage Foundation Backgrounder No. 1544, May 3, 2002, at http://www.heritage.org/Research/Taxes/BG1544.cfm; see also "The Argument for Reality-Based Scoring," Heritage Foundation Web Memo No. 92, March 29, 2002, at http://www.heritage.org/Research/Taxes/WM92.cfm, and Daniel R. Burton, "Reforming the Federal Tax Policy Process," Cato Policy Analysis, forthcoming December 2002.

[23]The variables changed in this simulation for the purpose of modeling FETT repeal are enumerated in the Appendix.

[24]Table 2 shows year-by-year estimates of how repeal of the FETTs would likely change major economic indicators.

[25]Congressional Budget Office, "The Budget and Economic Outlook: An Update," p. 48.

[26]CDA economists applied a staged process to calculate the additional capital gains tax collections. The first stage was to combine historical averages on federal estate tax returns from the IRS Statistics of Income Program and modified pro­jections from the Joint Committee on Taxation on the current-law capital gains tax exclusion at death. These together yielded a projection of the amount of taxable capital gains held in estates over and above the $1 million exemption, without taking into account the higher spousal exemption. The second stage was for CDA analysts to use historical averages to find how much the higher $3 million spousal exemption would subtract from the first projection of tax­able capital gains. The final stage involved applying the long-term capital gains tax rate to the modified projection for non-exempt taxable capital gains to create a projection of the additional capital gains tax collections under FETT repeal.

[27]This version of the model is especially adapted to embody economic and budgetary projections published by the CBO in August 2002.

[28]Readers interested in replicating this analysis should contact the author for further information on how the model was applied.

[29]Beach, "The Case for Repealing the Estate Tax," p. 26.

[30]NIPA stands for National Income and Product Accounts.

[31]Fullenbaum and McNeill, "The Effects of the Federal Estate and Gift Tax on the Aggregate Economy," pp. A1 and A2. These two authors cited four sources for this estimate. The first estimate, by Guest and Associates, L.L.C., was based upon survey data to find the amount that estate holders spent on federal estate tax planning and preparation during 1995; this amount was compared with 1995 FETT collections and yielded a ratio of 30 percent. The second estimate was based upon calcula­tions for FETT compliance costs by Kennesaw State University scholars Joseph Astrachan and Craig Aranoff; the cost was divided by an annual FETT collection total, resulting in a ratio of 32 percent. The third estimate was from Christopher E. Erblich of the Tax and Estate Planning Practice Group, who calculated both compliance and economic disincentive costs resulting from the U.S. federal tax system; Erblich's amount was divided by an annual total for FETT collection, yielding a ratio close to 31.2 percent. Finally, CDA economist William W. Beach provided an estimate of the 1995 cost of compliance with FETT that, when compared to 1995 FETT collections, resulted in a ratio of 29.8 percent.

[32]Poterba, "Estate Tax and After-Tax Investment Returns," p. 339.

Authors

Alfredo Goyburu

Policy Analyst, Transportation and Infrastructure